Misbehaving by Richard H. Thaler — Book Summary and Review

Misbehaving — Book Review

Misbehaving is the definitive book on Behavioral Economics, the one you can’t afford to miss. Probably one of the best books on economics psychology that I’ve read alongside Daniel Kahneman’s Thinking Fast and Slow and Predictably Irrational by Dan Ariely.

Misbehaving: The Making of Behavioral EconomicsMisbehaving: The Making of Behavioral Economics by Richard H. Thaler
My rating: 4 of 5 stars

This is the definitive book on Behavioral Economics, the one you can’t afford to miss. Probably one of the best books on economics psychology that I’ve read alongside Daniel Kahneman’s Thinking Fast and Slow and Predictably Irrational by Dan Ariely.

View all my reviews
Advertisements

Misbehaving — Book Summary

Misbehaving: Accounting for Human Behavior in Economics

Economics is the most influential of the social sciences because of its far-reaching foundation theories and their impact on people’s lives. These theories say that individuals always make optimal purchasing decisions which considering their budget, and needs and that free markets tend toward a state of equilibrium in which the supply of a good or service equals it’s demand.

But these assumptions are faulty at best since the tendency of the misbehaving tendency of human being. Ideal decision making is impossible. Consider supermarket shopping, with the countless goods options and variation available, how can any individuals always make the best choices? Optimizing is even harder in such tasks as choosing a spouse; high divorce rates suggest that marital selections are hardly optimal.

Unbiased decision making is another flawed staple of economic theory. Economic models have substituted the human being (Homo sapiens) for “a fictional creature called Homo economicus,” or “Econ,” a perfectly rational decision-maker who always optimizes. Real human decision making often tends to “misbehaving” in the artificial world of economics, so forecasts based on the rational behaviour of Econs are often if not always wrong. For example, few economists predicted the financial crisis of 2008 because it “simply could not happen” in their version of economic reality.

While economic models in which everyone behaves like an Econ still have value as “useful starting points” for accurate analyses, better explanations of the economy are emerging from behavioural economics, which incorporates misbehaving psychology and other social sciences into economics. It is in my opinion that social sciences and behavioural economics make the ‘economic model’ more humane. Since it incorporate our misbehaving ways.

Advertisements

The Endowment Effect

The endowment effect is one of many, predictable human misbehaviours that should limit analysts’ reliance on Econs’ theoretical behaviour. Unlike Econs, people value what they already own – their endowment– more than whatever they could acquire and add to it.

For example, consider the retail pricing of cash versus credit card purchases when credit cards first appeared. Because retailers had to pay fees to the credit card issuers, retailers wanted to charge customers more for credit card purchases. But the issuers insisted that if a retailer chose to set different prices, the normal price should be what credit card customers paid (normalization), while cash customers would get a discount off the regular price. Whether the price differential is a surcharge or a discount doesn’t matter to an Econ, since the two pricing policies are identical. However, the practice of calling the difference a discount helped the credit card industry. People tend to perceive a surcharge as an out-of-pocket expense, which they dislike while forgoing a cash discount is only an opportunity cost to which they’re indifferent.

Advertisements

Hindsight, Heuristics and Other Misbehaviors

Psychologist Baruch Fischhoff wrote a thesis on hindsight bias – that is, people’s tendency to believe, after an event’s outcome, that they always knew all along what the result would be. This propensity can hurt a company if, for example, mid-level executives risk their jobs if they promote projects that fail. For instance, a chief executive officer might fire talented staffers who were associated with an unsuccessful project just because the CEO believes the failure was predictable and thinks he or she always knew the project would flop. Sadly enough, this is most of the time are true, the staffer is the judge on their failure more often than their successes.

Fischhoff worked at the Hebrew University in Israel with two other academics – Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky – who published a paper entitled “Judgment Under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases.” They wrote that people have limited time and intelligence to make good judgments, so they try to reach decisions by using basic rules of thumb, or heuristics. Kahneman and Tversky contended that the use of heuristics can lead to predictable errors and biases.

A forerunner of Kahneman and Tversky, Herbert Simon wrote about his concept of the use of bounded rationality in individual decision making. He argues that most people don’t have the mental capacity to handle complicated problems. Economists believe that their models account for that possibility by including an “error term” in their calculations. Imagine a model for predicting the height children will attain at adulthood that uses their parents’ heights as a base. Tall adults tend to have tall offspring, so the model is accurate to some extent, though imperfect.

In economic terms, the model is reliable if its errors are “random,” meaning the frequency of overestimates and underestimates is equal so that the errors offset one another. Though economists believed the error term compensated for bounded rationality in their Econ-based models, Kahneman and Tversky’s work warned that rationality-based economic models could produce nonrandom errors.

Advertisements

Injecting Human Emotion into Expected Utility

In 1944, mathematician John von Neumann and economist Oskar Morgenstern published a paper that popularized their “expected utility theory,” which economists embraced as a guide to rational choice. The authors argued that the marginal utility of wealth – that is, the value of its incremental increases – will decline as a rational individual (an Econ) accumulates wealth.

Kahneman and Tversky developed “prospect theory,” a human-based alternative to the expected utility theory. Prospect theory says changes in wealth affect people more than their absolute levels of wealth. Individuals dislike losses about twice as much as they like gains. People exhibit their loss aversion when the intensity of their distress at losing $100 exceeds the intensity of their delight at gaining $100. An Econ, of course, would feel distressed or delight in equal measure.

Loss aversion (vary by circumstances) constitutes another common form of human misbehaviour that undermines economic convention. Investors who lose money may take unusually big risks to move their portfolios back to a break-even point.

Ain’t Misbehaving?

The influential philosopher Adam Smith famously used the metaphor of “an invisible hand” to describe how the independent actions of buyers and sellers make markets work for the benefit of society. The implication of the metaphor is that this unseen force somehow discourages irrational decision making that is detrimental to society. But the power of the invisible hand is “both overstated and mysterious.” The assertion is that markets somehow discipline people who are misbehaving, but no logical argument supports the notion that markets turn people into perfectly rational agents – that is, Econs.

The sunk-cost fallacy is another source of irrational behaviour that economics can’t explain. Economists say ignoring sunk costs is logical. An old maxim, “Don’t cry over spilt milk,” expresses the same idea. Imagine buying expensive shoes that end up hurting your feet. Many people will go on wearing them, despite the pain, because they refuse to acknowledge the loss, the sunk cost of an expensive uncomfortable shoe. Large-scale errors can stem from believing the sunk cost fallacy. The United States, for example, may have prolonged the Vietnam War because of a belief that Americans had sacrificed too much to withdraw from the conflict before it finally ended.

Advertisements

The Fairness Factor

Research shows that people believe companies are behaving unfairly when they raise prices to increase profits, but that they are acting appropriately when they raise prices to cover increased costs. Fairness can benefit firms, especially those that serve the same customers over the long term. Perceptions of fairness have their roots in the endowment effect. Buyers and sellers who become accustomed to the terms of their transactions develop a sense of entitlement and will perceive a downgrade of the terms as a loss.

Additional evidence that rational Econs are fundamentally different from real human beings emerges from a fairness game called the “public goods” game. The outcomes consistently show that some people are cooperative even when that behaviour is contrary to their own financial interests. Researchers give 10 players five $1 bills each and tell them they can anonymously contribute any amount (or none) to a public good. Researchers will then double their donations and distribute the proceeds equally to all the players. The logical individual strategy would be to make no contribution: If you donate $1, you will get back just 20 cents of your dollar with no acknowledgement of your generosity, while everyone else gains an incremental 20 cents. But in practice, players typically contribute about half their stakes, on average, to the public good.

Advertisements

Missing the Big Picture

The concept of narrow framing means viewing events or transactions separately, not as part of a larger body of experience. An investor’s reasons for focusing on events or items in isolation can include “myopic loss aversion.” In an experiment to demonstrate this aversion, investors who saw their portfolio results more frequently – and thus had a greater chance of seeing losses – invested with greater caution. Those who saw their results eight times annually put 41% of their portfolios in riskier stocks, but those who saw results once a year put 70% in shares.

Reconsidering the Efficient Market

The efficient market hypothesis holds that a share’s price reflects its true value. For a dividend-paying stock, that consists of the present value of future dividend payments. But in 1981, Robert Shiller, now a professor of economics at Yale University, published research showing that while this value was stable, the actual prices of dividend-paying stocks were extremely variable. Shiller thus dented the notion that the stock market is perfectly priced, but the debate over the efficient market hypothesis goes on.

The hypothesis would also predict, for example, that the price of shares in closed-end funds would equal their net asset value. Yet shares of closed-end funds usually sell at 10% to 20% discounts to the nett asset value. The efficient market hypothesis is a useful “normative” guide to how markets should work, but less effective as a “descriptive” tool for predicting real market behaviour.

Advertisements

Prodding the Public

Econs always act rationally, but flawed human beings make mistakes and sometimes need a “nudge” in the right direction. That’s why many companies automatically enrol new employees in retirement plans. Some firms obtain their employees’ consent to put more of their paychecks into savings as their wages rise. In another example of nudging, Amsterdam’s Schiphol International Airport encouraged men to take better aim when using airport urinals by placing the image of a housefly near the drain on each urinal. This reduced “spillage” by 80%.

A 2014 study calculated that 136 countries, including the US, have embraced behavioural sciences in at least some public policies. The United Kingdom has experimented with letters urging citizens to pay their delinquent taxes. The most effective missive included a nudge stating that the “great majority of people…pay their taxes on time” and that the neglectful taxpayer is in a tiny minority of those who don’t pay punctually. The new language raised the number of people paying their taxes on time by more than five percentage points.

Advertisements

Nudging the Profession

Since the 1970s, behavioural economics has transcended its former status as a “fringe operation” in the study of economics. Surprisingly, the behavioural school of thought has influenced finance more than any other industry due to its allegiance to fundamental theories that researchers can test using the sector’s massive trove of analyzable data.

But realistic behaviour-based thinking is still largely absent from the field of macroeconomics, where Econs roam free. The behavioural analysis could improve the success rate of tax cuts intended to ignite economic growth. And because people fear loss more than they like gains, mitigating the cost of business failures could encourage more entrepreneurialism.

Behavioural economics eventually may cease to exist as a special segment of the economics profession, and then economics will be “as behavioural as it needs to be.”

RICHARD H. THALER: WINNER OF THE 2017 NOBEL PRIZE IN ECONOMICS.Shortlisted for the Financial Times and McKinsey Business Book of the Year Award
ECONOMIST, FINANCIAL TIMES and EVENING STANDARD books of the year.

Buy the Book

READ MY OTHER BOOK SUMMARY AND REVIEW

Advertisements
Advertisements
Advertisements

Author: Muhamad Aarif

A notorious book addict by night and an oil and gas executive by day. As Mark Twain said, "The man who doesn't read good books has no advantage over the man who can't read them." So, read, read, and read some more.

Leave a Reply

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.